First-tier east asian high-performing asian economies là gì năm 2024

Mots clés : Nouveaux pays industrialisés ; Filière de production globalisée ; Diffusion des technologies ; Valeur ajoutée industrielle ; Conception des produits ; Stratégies de marques.

Key words : New industrialized countries ; Global commodity chain ; technology transfers ; industrial value adoled ; product design, brand strategies.

States and markets in East Asia 's "economic miracle"

Japan and the newly industrializing countries (NICs) of East Asia — South Korea, Taiwan, Hong Kong, and Singapore — have been dubbed "miracle economies" because of their unparalleled accomplishments in the latter half of the twentieth century. They registered record economic growth rates not only during the prosperous 1960s, when international trade and investment were expanding rapidly, but they also managed to sustain their dynamism through the 1970s and 1980s in the face of several oil price hikes, a global recession, and rising protectionism in their major export markets. In addition, the exceptionally rapid economic growth of the East Asian economies has been accompanied by high and rising per capita incomes, relatively low levels of inequality in wealth and income distribution, and dramatic improvements in other dimensions of human welfare, such as education, health, and housing.

In 1993, the World Bank published its much heralded study entitled The East Asian Miracle, which argues for the uniqueness of East Asia's record of rapid and sustained economic growth with social equity (1). Prompted by Japan's vocal dissatisfaction with the World Bank's overemphasis on macroeconomic issues in

(1) World Bank, The East Asian Miracle : Economic Growth and Public Policy (New York : Oxford University Press, 1993).

In the 1960s, the populations of East Asia and the rest of the developing world were growing quite rapidly, and many viewed this population growth with alarm. The governments of China, South Korea, Taiwan, Singapore, Thailand and Indonesia pursued policies designed to reduce rates of childbearing and slow population growth in the belief that to do otherwise would seriously impede development efforts. Among the countries of East and Southeast Asia, only Malaysia pursued a pro-natalist course.

The view that population growth slows economic growth was greeted by considerable skepticism in academic circles (). Economists were undoubtedly influenced by the neoclassical growth model which implies that population growth has a relatively modest effect on the level of per capita income during transitions and no effect at all on the steady-state growth path (). Moreover, simple empirical evidence bolstered the view that population growth was of secondary importance. In a bivariate comparison, population growth and growth in per capita income appeared to be entirely independent of one another ().

Evidence that is now emerging suggests that policymakers may have had it right and the academics may have had it wrong. Repeating Kelley’s simple but provocative exercise, Figure 1 plots growth in per capita income against growth of population for the 1960–2000 period. Assessed over this longer time period, there is a clear negative correlation between population growth and economic growth.

![An external file that holds a picture, illustration, etc. Object name is nihms82908f1.jpg](https://i0.wp.com/www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC2634856/bin/nihms82908f1.jpg)

Population Growth and Economic Growth, 1960–2000

East Asia’s experience is also broadly consistent with the view that population matters (; ). The East Asian countries adopted strong family planning programs, fertility rates dropped rapidly, population growth slowed and economic development accelerated.

Broad characterizations and simple statistical associations will only take us so far, however. The statistical relationship shown in Figure 1 may be spurious or the causality may go in the other direction and, in fact, population growth may have slowed as a consequence of rapid economic growth. Moreover, Figure 1 suggests that slowing population growth explains only a modest portion of East Asia’s economic success as the East Asian countries lie well above the regression line.

Neo-Malthusian studies of population and development have typically been concerned about the effects of fixed or inflexible resource constraints of one form or another. In contrast, most contemporary studies emphasize the role of the age structure. The potential significance of the population age structure is immediately apparent from Figure 2, which shows estimates of the age profiles of labor income and consumption for Taiwan in 1998 (Mason et al. forthcoming). The most striking feature of this chart is the extended period of life during which humans consume substantially more than they produce, roughly balanced by an extended period during which humans produce more than they consume. Enormous intergenerational reallocations of economic resources are occurring in Taiwan and in all other human populations, present and past, as well (, ).

![An external file that holds a picture, illustration, etc. Object name is nihms82908f2.jpg](https://i0.wp.com/www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC2634856/bin/nihms82908f2.jpg)

Consumption and Labor Income, Taiwan, 1998 (NT$)

Figure 2 is important for several reasons. First, it provides important information about inequality; that is, variation in mean consumption by age. In Taiwan, the profile is very flat. This is remarkable given the extraordinary rate of economic growth in Taiwan over the 40 years preceding 1998. The average lifetime earnings of those who are currently elderly were a small fraction of the lifetime earnings of those who are currently working, yet the elderly are supporting an average consumption nearly as high as are workers. That Taiwan has managed to achieve such an equitable intergenerational distribution of consumption is reflected in the low overall level of inequality for which Taiwan is known. Enormous reallocations across age groups and across generations were essential to this outcome.

Second, a direct effect of the population age structure on living standards is readily apparent from Figure 2. A population that is concentrated in the working ages can support a higher level of consumption than a population that is concentrated at ages where consumption exceeds production.

Less obvious, but of great importance, is the effect of the lifecycle reallocation system on the formation of both human and physical capital. The resources that flow from workers to children include spending on health and education that, in turn, determine the productivity of the next generation of workers. Reallocations from the working years to retirement years are, in part, realized by saving and the accumulation of physical capital. Increases in the expected duration of old-age dependency provides a powerful incentive for increased saving.

In the next section, we describe important and distinctive features of East Asia’s demographic transition. The transition is a global phenomenon, but there are important differences across countries and regions, especially in the trends in age structure. In the following sections, we discuss the implications for East Asian economic growth. Our thesis is that accelerated growth in the region can be traced to two demographic dividends.

DEMOGRAPHIC TRANSITION: EAST ASIAN STYLE

The demographic transition began much later in East Asia than in the West. Even in Japan, life expectancy at birth was stagnant at around 45 years through the first half of the 20th century. Rapid improvements came immediately following the end of World War II, but in 1960, Japan still had the lowest life expectancy at birth of any OECD country. Mortality conditions in other countries of Asia (for which data were available) were worse than in Japan. In India, for example, life expectancy was only 24 years in 1891–1911. In China, life expectancy was only 24 years in 1929–30. In contrast, life expectancy had reached 56 in Sweden, 50 in the United Kingdom and 47 in the United States by 1900 ().

The transition from high to low fertility also began later in Asia than in the West. In Japan, childbearing began to decline in the 1930s. After a short-lived post–World War II baby boom, the total fertility rate declined rapidly to about two births per woman in 1960. Other Asian countries did not experience any significant decline in fertility until 1960 or later. In contrast, fertility decline began in the mid-18th century in France and in the mid-19th century in the U.S. In both countries, the total fertility rate reached two births per woman much earlier than in Asia.

The large differences between fertility and mortality in East and Southeast Asia had important effects on two additional demographic features of the region: population growth and age structure. The baby boom fueled population growth in the West. The annual growth rate for 1950–73 increased to 0.8 percent per year in the average Western European country. The U.S. grew much faster at 1.4 percent per year. Population growth in China, Indonesia and South Korea exceeded 2 percent per year during the same period. In the Philippines, Taiwan and Thailand, the rates exceeded 3 percent per year (). Among Asian countries, only Japan had population growth of close to 1 percent per year at that time.

Although the trends in dependency in Asia and the West were about to diverge, in 1900 there were no apparent differences in the levels of dependency (Figure 3). Based on available data, there were about 0.60 to 0.75 persons in the dependent ages (0–14 or 60+ or 65+ depending on the source) for every person in the working ages (15–59 or 15–64 depending on the source). Dependency was falling in the West, however, and rising in the East. By 1950, dependency ratios had dropped to about 0.5 in the U.S., Sweden and other European countries. In contrast, in Taiwan, Indonesia, the Philippines and Thailand, the dependency ratio was close to 0.9 in 1950 and still rising ().

![An external file that holds a picture, illustration, etc. Object name is nihms82908f3.jpg](https://i0.wp.com/www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC2634856/bin/nihms82908f3.jpg)

Age Structure, Selected Countries, 1900–2000

Beginning between 1960 and 1970, the East Asian countries began to experience a precipitous decline in their dependency ratios as a direct consequence of rapid fertility decline. The trend in Japan is somewhat distinctive. It followed the Asian pattern during the early 20th century, but its dependency ratio went into rapid descent over a period of three decades from 1940 to 1970.

By 2000, the dependency ratios in Japan, Thailand and Taiwan were actually lower than in the U.S. and Sweden. Indonesia’s decline has also been quite rapid although its dependency ratio remains somewhat above values found in the West. The decline in the Philippines has been more gradual, reflecting the slower decline in fertility, and it too has a dependency ratio higher than in the West.

DID DEMOGRAPHY MATTER IN EAST ASIA?

We use an elaboration of the neoclassical growth model to frame our analysis (; ). Defining the effective number of consumers (N) and the effective number of producers (L) as:

N(t)=∑a=0100α(a)P(a,t)L(t)=∑a=0100γ(a)P(a,t)

(1)

where P(a,t), the population of each age, is weighted to reflect variation in “consumption needs” or variation in productivity. Output per effective consumer is defined by:

Y(t)N(t)=L(t)N(t)×Y(t)L(t)

(2)

or the product of the support ratio (L/N) and output per effective worker.

is expressed in growth terms as:

y.(t)=L.(t)−N.(t)+y.l(t).

(3)

The rate of growth in output per effective consumer (ẏ) is the rate of growth of the effective labor force (L̇) less the rate of growth of the number of effective consumers (Ṅ) plus the rate of growth in output per worker (ẏl). In the original Solow formulation, the population is not distinguished from the labor force. This is an appropriate assumption in steady-state, but during the demographic transition, labor force growth and population growth diverge for decades with important implications for growth in per capita income. This phenomenon, known as the demographic dividend, is discussed in greater detail below.

Output is produced by two factors: capital and augmented labor. Augmented labor is determined, in turn, as the product of the effective labor force and productivity which is assumed to grow at a constant rate λ. The production function is constant returns to scale (i.e., Cobb-Douglas). Growth in output per effective worker is given by:

where k̇ is the rate of growth of capital per augmented worker and β is the elasticity of output with respect to capital. The growth of capital per worker is given by:

In steady-state equilibrium, k̇ = 0 and L̇ = Ṅ. Growth in output per worker and output per effective consumer are determined entirely by technological progress, i.e., productivity increases. Neither the demographic dividend nor saving rates influence the rate of growth. During transition, however, both the saving rate and the demographic dividend influence growth in per capita income.

An extensive empirical literature on East Asia’s economic growth demonstrates that the region is far from equilibrium (; ). The importance of productivity growth is debated, but the importance of capital deepening is not. Capital per worker grew in excess of 6 percent per annum in Japan, South Korea, Taiwan and Thailand, for example, between 1965 and 1990 ().

The Solow model identifies two sources of capital deepening: an increase in the rate of saving and a decline in the rate of labor force growth. In many East Asian countries, wartime destruction had resulted in a below-equilibrium capital-labor ratio, and some capital deepening was a matter of recovery to pre-war levels. Saving rates were quite low in the 1950s and early 1960s, and to some extent foreign aid contributed to the recovery. The key to capital deepening in East Asia, however, has been the extraordinary rise in saving rates throughout the region.

Given the speed of fertility decline, one might easily presume that labor force growth slowed, contributing further to capital deepening. Labor force growth peaked in the 1970s in Malaysia, the Philippines, Singapore, Thailand, China and South Korea, but the declines have been relatively modest (). Several factors account for this. One is that mortality rates were also declining, which offset to some extent the effect of the fertility decline on population growth. A second factor is that most of the slowdown in population growth that occurred was due to slower growth in the number of dependents. By and large, the number of children stopped growing, but the number of adults continued to grow. Third, there were substantial increases in female labor force participation in many countries in the region.

Based on this brief and highly stylized synopsis of East Asia’s economic growth, two issues are important. The first is whether or not there was a substantial divergence between growth in the effective labor force and the effective number of consumers (i.e., the first demographic dividend). The second is whether the rapid increase in aggregate saving rates represents a second dividend.

The First Demographic Dividend

The divergence between the effective number of consumers and producers is an inherent part of the demographic transition. The widespread nature of this phenomenon is apparent in Figure 4, which plots the growth of the effective number of consumers against the growth of the effective number of producers for the 1960–2000 period. The values are constructed using United Nation’s population estimates for all countries in the U.N. system (). Age-specific weights for consumption and production are estimated using the 1998 Family Income and Expenditure Survey for Taiwan (Figure 1).

![An external file that holds a picture, illustration, etc. Object name is nihms82908f4.jpg](https://i0.wp.com/www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC2634856/bin/nihms82908f4.jpg)

Changes in Age Structure East and Southeast Asia, Rest of the World 1960–2000

A few countries lie directly on the 45° line with identical growth rates in the effective labor force and the effective number of consumers. Many African countries and a few Asian countries lie above the 45° line. In these countries, the demographic transition has proceeded slowly and birth rates are relatively high; as such, the effective number of consumers grew more rapidly than the effective number of producers between 1960 and 2000.

However, most countries of the world reaped a demographic dividend between 1960 and 2000. In Asia, Latin America and the West, the number of effective consumers grew more slowly than the number of effective producers. As a result, output per effective consumer grew more rapidly than output per worker. The estimates of the 1960–2000 dividend are summarized in Table 1. For the world as a whole, the effective labor force grew at an annual rate of 2.0 percent per year while the number of effective consumers grew at an annual rate of 1.8 percent. The difference—0.2 percent per year—is the annual global demographic dividend for the 1960–2000 period. The cumulative effect over the entire period was to increase income per effective consumer by 8.2 percent, a modest positive effect.

Table 1

Demographic Dividend, 1960–2000. Major Regions of the World, High Performing Countries of East Asia.

Annual Growth Rate(%), 1960–2000


Annual average dividend (%)Cumulative effect on output per effective consumer (%)Effective labor forceEffective ConsumersWorld2.011.810.208.2More developed regions0.920.740.187.6Less developed regions2.432.180.2510.7Least developed countries2.422.50−0.08−3.0Africa2.602.64−0.05−1.8Asia2.322.020.2912.5Europe0.680.530.156.1Latin America and Caribbean2.642.280.3615.6Northern America1.431.170.2610.8Oceania1.911.730.187.5China2.291.810.4821.2China, Hong Kong SAR2.702.220.4821.3Japan1.120.870.2510.6Republic of Korea2.521.790.7333.9Indonesia2.382.080.3012.7Malaysia3.062.630.4318.8Singapore3.262.490.7736.1Thailand3.002.340.6630.2

The demographic dividend was slightly greater in the less-developed regions than the more-developed regions, although the difference is quite small. The least-developed countries, mostly African countries, did not benefit at all from changes in age structure. Other major regions of the world experienced a small demographic dividend. The cumulative effect varied from a low of 6.1 percent in Europe to 15.6 percent in Latin America and the Caribbean.

The cumulative effect of the demographic dividend in Asia was to increase output per effective consumer by 12.5 percent between 1960 and 2000. Given the enormous diversity of Asia, however, regional aggregations are not terribly useful. The demographic dividend was substantially larger in the high-performing economies of East Asia. In Singapore and South Korea, for example, the demographic dividend increased annual growth in income per effective consumer by about three-quarters of a percentage point over the 40-year period. Thailand’s growth was higher by two-thirds of a percentage point, and China and Hong Kong benefited by one-half of a percentage point. The cumulative effect was to raise output per effective consumer by about 20 percent in China, 30 percent in Thailand, 34 percent in South Korea and 36 percent in Singapore.

Whether the East Asian values are considered small or not depends on the point of reference. As compared with long-term productivity growth in the U.S., typically estimated at 1.0–1.5 percent per year, the demographic dividend is quite significant. Compared with the high rates of economic growth achieved in East Asia, however, the demographic dividend appears to be more modest. Table 2 presents calculations for the four countries with the largest dividends in Table 1. In these four countries, between 1960 and 2000, GDP per effective consumer grew at an annual rate ranging from 4.3 percent in Thailand to 5.7 percent in Singapore. The demographic dividend accounted for 9.2 percent of China’s growth and up to 15.5 percent of Thailand’s growth. Using a slightly different approach, estimates that the demographic dividend accounted for 19.2 percent of Taiwan’s economic growth between 1965 and 1990.

Table 2

Contribution of Demographic Dividend to East Asian Economic Growth.

Growth rate (%)


Demographic dividendDividend as percent of economic growthGDPEffective number of consumersGDP per effective consumerChina7.01.85.20.59.2Korea, Rep.7.31.85.50.713.2Singapore8.22.55.70.813.6Thailand6.62.34.30.715.5

A Second Dividend: Demography and Capital Deepening

The existence and potential importance of the demographic dividend has gained relatively wide acceptance in recent years (; ). Also widely appreciated is the transitory nature of the demographic dividend. Working age populations are growing much more slowly and are beginning to decline in some countries, while the number of pensioners is continuing to grow rapidly. By 2050, the demographic dividend will have essentially disappeared in the West, Japan, Hong Kong and Singapore. Other Asian countries will follow ().

The prospect of rapid growth in the numbers of retired elderly—and the accompanying strains on public pension and health care systems—has led to considerable pessimism about economic performance over the coming decades. Rather than being a source of decline, however, population aging may be the source of a second demographic dividend.

The prospects of a longer life and an extended period of retirement represent a powerful saving incentive for those in their working ages. Where familial support systems are especially strong, saving incentives may be undermined. However, with fertility decline and increases in life expectancy, familial support systems will experience the same strains widely discussed with respect to public pension systems. The possibility that these systems will erode looms large. Indeed, rapid decline has already begun in several Asian countries.

The combined effects of aging and declining familial support systems may have a large effect on lifecycle saving and the demand for wealth. use a simulation model to trace out the complex effects of demographic change and the decline of familial support systems on saving and wealth based on the experience of Taiwan. They show that the combined effects of increased life expectancy and familial support systems are sufficient to produce a threefold increase in the capital-output ratio during the first half of the 21st century. Capital deepening of this magnitude could produce an increase in output per worker by an additional 1.1 percent per year ().

The possibility that demographic factors have led to more rapid economic growth because of their effects on aggregate saving rates is broadly consistent with the East Asian experience. As noted above, the rise in saving rates in East Asia led to rapid capital deepening and, in conjunction with a variety of other well-known factors, growth in output per worker. Several recent empirical studies have found that the decline in youth dependency had an enormous effect on aggregate saving rates. Macroeconometric studies by Kelley and Schmidt (1995), and find large, statistically significant effects of age structure on aggregate saving rates. Over the course of a demographic transition along the lines experienced in East Asia, the estimates by Williamson and Higgins and by Toh imply that demographic change would have produced an increase in gross national saving rates by 43 and 45 percentage points, respectively. Analysis by Kelley and Schmidt implies a smaller but still enormous increase of 25 percentage points ().

Other approaches suggest a more modest though still important effect. Simulation analysis of lifecycle saving suggests that demographic factors could account for no more than a 14.5 percentage point increase in saving rates (). calculate that changes in age structure over the demographic transition could have produced an increase of 6.5 percentage points.

Reaching any definitive conclusion about how changes in youth dependency contributed to higher saving rates and capital deepening in East Asia requires some reconciliation of these diverse results. First, the studies use different measures of saving. The macro-based estimates analyze gross national saving, whereas micro-based estimates focus on household saving rates. Thus, macro-based estimates would capture effects on government and saving rates while micro-based estimates would not. Macro-based estimates would also capture effects on private saving that is not included in household saving rates. Second, the methodology used in the Deaton and Paxson analysis relies on estimating age profiles of consumption and earning which are then held constant in order to assess the effects of changing age structure. Such an approach is useful for examining compositional effects, but it excludes from consideration the effects of age structure on the age profiles of consumption and earning. Third, to the extent that changes in childbearing are inducing shifts away from familial transfer systems, the Deaton and Paxson approach would not capture any substitution of saving for family transfers.

At the same time, there are many problems with estimates that are based on international aggregate panel data. Two issues seem to be particularly important. First, results are sensitive to model specification and sample selection. Second, endogenity is a constant issue. Under these circumstances, the large estimated effects of youth dependency are likely to be discounted by skeptics.

The effect of life expectancy on saving has received relatively little attention in the literature since pathbreaking work. A number of empirical studies have found that an increase in life expectancy leads to higher saving rates (; ; ; ; ). Why saving would be influenced by increases in longevity is easily understood in the context of the lifecycle model. If gains in life expectancy lead to an increase in the duration of retirement, lifecycle individuals must increase their saving during the working years so as to finance the greater consumption needed during the retirement years. Early in the demographic transition, most of the gains in life expectancy are achieved through reductions in infant and child mortality with no effect on the duration of retirement. Later in the demographic transition, the gains in life come at later ages increasing the duration of retirement in the face of a constant or declining age at retirement.

Other than the simple lifecycle argument, there are other ways that changes in mortality may influence saving. For example, the age at death has become more compressed and, hence, more predictable. This has led to a decline in uncertainty about the age of death and, perhaps, a decline in the demand for wealth as insurance against longevity risk. argue that a fall in mortality has an “uncertainty effect” and a “horizon effect” on retirement. The uncertainty effect follows from the decline in uncertainty about the age at death which leads individuals to attach greater value to retirement (leisure). Thus, they retire at a younger age and save more while young. The horizon effect leads individuals to delay their retirement in order to finance the additional consumption associated with a later age at death.

In a recent study, uses a two-generation OLG model to investigate the effects of improvements in adult mortality on aggregate saving. She shows that in steady-state, the aggregate saving rate induced by lifecycle behavior will increase with adult longevity in a growing economy. This is consistent with the standard lifecycle saving model in that changes in the age profile of consumption have no effect on aggregate saving in a zero-growth economy (). The effect of an increase in the mean age of consumption on saving interacts with the rate of economic growth (, ). These features of the steady-state lifecycle saving model are capture by the variable rate-of-growth saving model:

where q measures adult survival and g is the real rate of growth of total income. The interactive feature of the specification is particularly important to understanding the East Asian experience because changes in survival have a much larger effect in rapidly growing economies such as those found in East Asia.

The important contribution of Kinugasa’s analysis is the extension of the OLG model to out-of-steady-state effects. She shows that an increase in the survival rate has a positive effect on saving that is independent of the rate of growth of income. Thus, the effects of improvements in adult survival on saving are captured by:

s = β0 + β1qg + β2Δq + ε.

(7)

Under this formulation, the speed of the mortality transition matters. A rapid mortality transition results in higher saving rates as adult survival reaches higher levels, but during the transition saving is given an extra boost. Why does this occur? When mortality is improving rapidly, the gap between current wealth and desired wealth is greater. Thus, higher saving is required to achieve the desired level of wealth.

Detailed empirical results are presented in and and only a brief summary is offered here. Table 3 reports OLS and 2SLS estimates of the determinant of the national saving rate, using a sample restricted to Western countries and high-performing East-Asian countries. In other regions of the world, the rate of change in adult survival does not have a statistically significant positive effect on the national saving rate (; ).

Table 3

Regression estimates of gross national saving rates, Western and East Asian Sample, 1960–2000.

OLS Estimates2SLS Estimates


CoefficientsStandard errorsCoefficientsStandard errorsqg9.5313.647 ***15.9233.673 ***Δq(5 years)1.4250.736 **1.3910.834 *D1·g−2.7381.054 ***−1.3621.140 ***g−3.7532.403 ***−7.3372.472PRI0.0370.020 *0.0290.021year700.0090.0160.0100.016year75−0.0270.016 *−0.0240.016year80−0.0280.020−0.0170.024year85−0.0010.0170.0160.020year90−0.0350.017−0.0270.019year95−0.0040.0200.0180.023Asia0.1110.016 *0.0910.020 ***Constant0.1640.024 ***0.1410.029 ***


Adjusted R20.4140.384N190190P-value, g0.0000.000g effect0.0430.583P-value, year dummies0.0150.001P-value,Hausman0.000

For the West and high-performing East Asian countries, the OLS and 2SLS results confirm the importance of demographic factors and the hypotheses advanced by Kinugasa. The estimated effects of the interaction of adult survival and GDP growth (qg) are statistically significantly at the 1-percent level in both the OLS and 2SLS regressions. The effect of an increase in the level of the survival rate on the national saving rate is positive if GDP is growing. The rate of change of the survival rate has a positive and statistically significant effect at the 5-percent level in the OLS analysis and the 10-percent level in the 2SLS analysis.

The estimated effect of youth dependency, interacted with GDP growth, is statistically significant in the OLS analysis, but not in the 2SLS analysis. The rate of growth effect is statistically significant and, at the means of D1 and q, positive. The estimated coefficients of price of investment goods (PRI) are positive and statistically significant in both regressions, implying that the substitution effect of increases in interest rates dominates the wealth effect. The estimated coefficient of the dummy variable for East Asian countries is positive and statistically significant, implying that the variables in the regression model do not fully account for East Asia’s high saving rates.

The importance of changes in the youth dependency ratio and adult survival are most easily assessed using counterfactual analysis. The values presented in Table 4 assess the effect of the demographic variables by holding all other independent variables constant at the mean value for all countries and periods in the sample. The values in column (1) show the combined effect of changes in adult survival and youth dependency, while the separate effects of youth dependency are reported in column (2) and of adult survival in column (3). The effect of adult survival is assessed by allowing both the level of survival and the rate of change of survival to vary in the calculations. All values are based on the OLS estimates.

Table 4

Counterfactual analysis given world-wide means for control variables.

Western and East Asian Sample


(1) Changing q and D1(2) Changing D1(3) Changing q19650.21650.19960.216519700.22140.20110.219919750.23380.20490.228519800.24350.20910.233919850.25100.21340.237219900.25580.21630.239219950.25620.21860.2373



Western Sample


East Asian Sample


Other Countries


(1) Changing q and D1(2) Changing D1(3) Changing q(1) Changing q and D1(2) Changing D1(3) Changing q(1) Changing q and D1(2) Changing D1(3) Changing q


19650.22410.21010.22410.17660.14430.17660.13220.10820.132219700.22730.21110.22640.19020.14830.18620.13640.10870.135919750.23750.21410.23340.21350.15550.20230.14440.11030.142219800.24720.21760.23970.22240.16340.20320.15380.11330.148719850.25420.22140.24290.23240.17000.20670.16040.11520.153419900.25740.22340.24420.24610.17740.21290.16440.11790.154719950.25810.22520.24310.24300.18170.20560.15610.12010.1441

The first set of results in Table 4 presents the calculated effects of demographic variables on saving using the global changes in youth dependency and adult survival. The combined effect was to increase saving rates by about 20 percent, with the gains concentrated between 1965 and 1985. Survival and youth dependency had about equal effects.

There are important regional differences because of differences in demographic experiences. In East Asia, the national saving rate increased by 3.7 percentage points due to the decline in child dependency. For the Western countries and for developing countries outside of East Asia, the decline in youth dependency was more modest, leading to an increase in national saving rates of only 1.5 and 1.2 percentage points, respectively.

Changes in adult survival also had a greater effect in the high-performing East Asian countries than elsewhere. In East Asia, saving rates increased by 2.9 percentage points due to the increase in adult survival. In the West, the increase was 1.9 percentage points and in the rest of the developing world, the increase was 1.2 percentage points.

The calculations presented in Table 4 assume that the rate of economic growth for each region was equal to the global average; thus, they do not take into account the interaction between economic growth and demographic variables. Because East Asian economic growth was so high, however, demographic variables had a much larger effect on aggregate saving rates. Table 5 repeats the analysis presented in Table 4, but uses regional means rather than global means for the nondemographic variables. Calculated in this manner, aggregate saving rates increased by 13.6 percentage points between 1965 and 1995 due to the decline in child dependency and the rise in adult survival. Again the change in child dependency and adult survival were about equally important. Declining child dependency led to a rise in saving rates by 6.9 percentage points. Improvements in adult survival led to a rise in saving rates by 6.7 percentage points. Observed saving rates increased by 14.7 percentage points in East Asia during this period. Hence, demographic change accounted for 92 percent of the increase in East Asian saving rates.

Table 5

Counterfactual analysis given regional means for control variables.

Western Sample


East Asian Sample


Other Countries


(1) Changing q and D1(2) Changing D1(3) Changing q(1) Changing q and D1(2) Changing D1(3) Changing q(1) Changing q and D1(2) Changing D1(3) Changing q19650.20730.19330.20730.21920.18690.21920.13310.10900.132219700.20980.19410.20900.24330.19420.23600.13790.10960.135919750.21900.19670.21550.28120.20750.26060.14660.11140.142219800.22750.19960.22120.30370.22210.26850.15690.11470.148719850.23340.20290.22370.32520.23400.27800.16430.11670.153419900.23590.20460.22450.35100.24770.29020.16910.11980.154719950.23610.20610.22330.35490.25550.28630.16080.12210.1441

The estimated demographic effects on saving, though large, are more modest than those found in other recent empirical studies of age structure based on cross-national regression methods described above. The results presented here are more consistent with micro-based estimates such as Deaton and Paxson’s estimate that household saving rates rise by 6.5 percentage points due to changes in age structure (as compared with 6.9 percentage points here). The combined effect of declining child dependency and increasing life expectancy is quite similar to that found in the simulations where the combined effects of East Asian–style fertility and mortality change were found to have led to an increase in saving rates of 14.5 percentage points (as compared with 13.6 percentage points here).

These results clearly point to a second demographic dividend in East Asia. The decline in fertility and the rise in adult mortality, which will lead to rapid population aging, have also led to higher saving rates and rapid accumulation of wealth. Assessing the implications for economic growth would require a simulation analysis that incorporates our saving estimates. We do not undertake such an analysis here, but a recent analysis by concludes that per capita income could grow more rapidly—by 1.1 percent per annum over the next 50 years—due to the effects of demographic change on the accumulation of wealth.

QUALIFICATIONS AND CONCLUSIONS

Obtaining reliable estimates of the effects of demographic variables on saving is a difficult enterprise. Cross-national panel data can be used to estimate only relatively parsimonious models. Thus, the danger that estimated effects are spurious is a serious problem. Demographic variables tend to change gradually and are highly correlated; this makes it difficult to obtain reliable estimates of the separate effects of mortality and fertility. There are some instances where countries experience demographic shocks that could be explored. Two serious problems would have to be surmounted however. The first is that the shocks are typically accompanied by (or caused by) other changes that have their own implications. The experience of the transition economies comes to mind. The second problem is that the interest here is in long-term processes rather than short-term fluctuations. Incentives to save depend on expectations about the long-term trends in adult survival and not on short-term fluctuations in mortality, except insofar as they influence expectations in unknown ways. The consistency between the macro-based saving estimates presented here with the micro-based estimates and simulation results is reassuring, but application of the Kinugasa saving model to other developing regions of the world yields estimates that do not support the strong role of demographic factors found for the West and East Asian countries.

One possibility is that changes in fertility and mortality have been so gradual that it is difficult to obtain precise estimates of their effects. Another likely possibility is that the responses in saving are conditioned by the political, economic and social institutions of the countries experiencing demographic change. Of particular relevance here is the existence and form of support systems for the elderly. State-sponsored unfunded pension systems clearly undermine the incentive effects of fertility and mortality change, as is widely recognized in the literature on public pension reform. Perhaps East Asian saving rates responded more to demographic variables than Latin American saving rates because East Asian countries have relied much less on PAYGO pension systems than have Latin American countries.

Uncertainties remain about the contribution of fertility decline and increased longevity to the tremendous increase in saving rates in East Asia. Clearly, the widespread presumption that population aging is bad for economic growth is unwarranted. The rate of economic growth will surely decline with the passing of the first demographic dividend. Countries which are relying excessively on transfer systems to support the needs of the elderly will not benefit from the second dividend. However, for countries that encourage capital accumulation as a means of meeting retirement needs, aging can serve as a fundamental force for creating a wealthier and more prosperous society.

Footnotes

*Prepared for the Conference on Miracles and Mirages in East Asian Economic Development, Honolulu, Hawaii, May 22, 2004. This paper was written to honor Professor Seiji Naya for his many contributions to the University, to the State of Hawaii, and to understanding economic development in Asia. Mason’s research was supported by the National Institutes of Health: NIA, R01-AG025488, and by MEXT Academic Frontier.

1Given constant fertility and mortality rates and ignoring migration, populations eventually become stable. Under these conditions, all age groups grow at the same rate and the age distribution of the population is unchanging. Given constant labor force participation rates, the labor force and the population grow at the same rate.

2The productivity weights and consumption weights are estimated using standard procedures. The productivity weights are proportional to average earnings classified by age. The consumption weights are based on estimates of the allocation of household consumption among household members using a variant of Engel’s method. Within a household, child weights are about half of adult weights while the weights of seniors are about 80 percent of prime age adults. Lai and Maliki (2004) provide details of the estimation methods employed.

3Although annuities insure against longevity risk, the market is relatively thin, subject to moral hazard, and expensive even in the U.S. In Asian countries and even Japan, there is essentially no market. Hence, reliance on annuities as protection against longevity risk is relatively limited.

4The Western countries are the European countries (Albania, Austria, Belgium, Bulgaria, Switzerland, Denmark, Spain, Finland, France, United Kingdom, Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Italy, Macedonia, Netherlands, Norway, New Zealand, Poland, Portugal, Romania, Russia, Slovak Republic, Slovenia, Sweden and Turkey), the United States, Australia and New Zealand. The high-performing East Asian countries are Japan, Korea, Thailand and Malaysia. China was excluded because of its tremendous structural change during the period of analysis, Taiwan because of missing data, and Singapore and Hong Kong because they are city-states.

5The 2SLS estimates assume that GDP growth is endogenous. The P-value for the Hausman test is 0.000, which implies that GDP growth is endogenous.

Publisher's Disclaimer: This is a PDF file of an unedited manuscript that has been accepted for publication. As a service to our customers we are providing this early version of the manuscript. The manuscript will undergo copyediting, typesetting, and review of the resulting proof before it is published in its final citable form. Please note that during the production process errors may be discovered which could affect the content, and all legal disclaimers that apply to the journal pertain.

Contributor Information

ANDREW MASON, Dept. of Economics, University of Hawai’i-Mânoa, Honolulu, Hawaii, and Population and Health Studies, East-West Center, Honolulu, Hawaii, TEL: 808-9447455, FAX: 808-9447490, EMAIL: UDE.IIAWAH@NOSAMA.

TOMOKO KINUGASA, Graduate School of Economics, Kobe University, Kobe, Japan.

References

  • Bauer J. Demographic change, development and the economic status of women in East Asia. In: Mason A, editor. Population Change and Economic Development in East Asia: Challenges Met, Opportunities Seized. Stanford: Stanford University Press; 2001. [Google Scholar]
  • Bloom DE, Canning D, et al. Longevity and life-cycle savings. Scandinavian Journal of Economics. 2003;105(3):319–38. [Google Scholar]
  • Bloom DE, Canning D, et al. The Demographic Dividend: A New Perspective on the Economic Consequences of Population Change. Santa Monica, CA: RAND; 2002. [Google Scholar]
  • Bloom DE, Williamson JG. Demographic transitions and economic miracles in emerging Asia. World Bank Economic Review. 1998;12(3):419–56. [Google Scholar]
  • Cutler DM, Poterba JM, et al. Mit. 1990. An Aging Society: Opportunity or Challenge? [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • Deaton A, Paxson CH. Growth, demographic structure, and national saving in Taiwan. In: Lee R, Chu CYC, editors. Population and Economic Change in East Asia, A Supplement to Population and Development Review. New York: Population Council; 2000. [Google Scholar]
  • Higgins M, Williamson JG. Age structure dynamics in Asia and dependence on foreign capital. Population and Development Review. 1997;23(2):261–93. [Google Scholar]
  • Kageyama J. The effects of a continuous increase in lifetime on saving. Review of Income and Wealth. 2003;49(2):163–83. [Google Scholar]
  • Kalemli-Ozcan S, Weil DN. Mortality change, the uncertainty effect, and retirement. NBER Working Papers, no 8742 2002 [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • Kelley AC. Economic consequences of population change in the Third World. Journal of Economic Literature. 1988;26(4):1685–728. [Google Scholar]
  • Kelley AC, Schmidt RM. Saving, dependency and development. Journal of Population Economics. 1996;9(4):365–86. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • Kinugasa T. PhD Dissertation. University of Hawaii; Manoa, Honolulu, Hawaii: 2004. Life expectancy, labor force, and saving. [Google Scholar]
  • Kinugasa T, Mason A. Why Nations Become Wealthy: The Effects of Adult Longevity on Saving. World Development. 2007;35(1):1–23. [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • La Croix SJ, Mason A, et al. Population and globalization. Southeast Asian Studies. 2003;40(3):240–67. [Google Scholar]
  • Lee RD. Intergenerational transfers and the economic life cycle: a cross-cultural perspective. In: Mason A, Tapinos G, editors. Sharing the Wealth: Demographic Change and Economic Transfers Between Generations. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 2000. [Google Scholar] Lee R, Lee S-H, Mason A. Charting the Economic Lifecycle. In: Prskawetz A, Bloom DE, Lutz W, editors. Population Aging, Human Capital Accumulation, and Productivity Growth, a supplement to Population and Development Review 33.